42. Time Inconsistency of Ramsey Plans#
In addition to what’s in Anaconda, this lecture will need the following libraries:
!pip install --upgrade quantecon
Show code cell output
Requirement already satisfied: quantecon in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (0.7.2)
Requirement already satisfied: numba>=0.49.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (0.60.0)
Requirement already satisfied: numpy>=1.17.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (1.26.4)
Requirement already satisfied: requests in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (2.32.3)
Requirement already satisfied: scipy>=1.5.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (1.13.1)
Requirement already satisfied: sympy in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (1.13.2)
Requirement already satisfied: llvmlite<0.44,>=0.43.0dev0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from numba>=0.49.0->quantecon) (0.43.0)
Requirement already satisfied: charset-normalizer<4,>=2 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (3.3.2)
Requirement already satisfied: idna<4,>=2.5 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (3.7)
Requirement already satisfied: urllib3<3,>=1.21.1 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (2.2.3)
Requirement already satisfied: certifi>=2017.4.17 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (2024.8.30)
Requirement already satisfied: mpmath<1.4,>=1.1.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from sympy->quantecon) (1.3.0)
42.1. Overview#
This lecture describes several linear-quadratic versions of a model that Guillermo Calvo [Calvo, 1978] used to illustrate the time inconsistency of optimal government plans.
Like Chang [Chang, 1998], we use these models as laboratories in which to explore consequences of timing protocols for government decision making.
The models focus attention on intertemporal tradeoffs between
welfare benefits that anticipations of future deflation generate by decreasing costs of holding real money balances and thereby increasing a representative agent’s liquidity, as measured by his or her holdings of real money balances, and
costs associated with the distorting taxes that the government must levy in order to acquire the paper money that it will destroy in order to generate anticipated deflation
The models feature
rational expectations
several explicit timing protocols
costly government actions at all dates \(t \geq 1\) that increase household utilities at dates before \(t\)
sets of Bellman equations, one set for each timing protocol
for example, in a timing protocol used to pose a Ramsey plan, a government chooses an infinite sequence of money supply growth rates once and for all at time \(0\).
in this timing protocol, there are two value functions and associated Bellman equations, one that expresses a representative private expectation of future inflation as a function of current and future government actions, another that describes the value function of a Ramsey planner
in other timing protocols, other Bellman equations and associated value functions will appear
A theme of this lecture is that timing protocols affect outcomes.
We’ll use ideas from papers by Cagan [Cagan, 1956], Calvo [Calvo, 1978], and Chang [Chang, 1998] as well as from chapter 19 of [Ljungqvist and Sargent, 2018].
In addition, we’ll use ideas from linear-quadratic dynamic programming described in Linear Quadratic Control as applied to Ramsey problems in Stackelberg plans.
We specify model fundamentals in ways that allow us to use linear-quadratic discounted dynamic programming to compute an optimal government plan under each of our timing protocols.
A sister lecture Machine Learning a Ramsey Plan studies some of the same models but does not use dynamic programming.
Instead it uses a machine learning approach that does not explicitly recognize the recursive structure structure of the Ramsey problem that Chang [Chang, 1998] saw and that we exploit in this lecture.
In addition to what’s in Anaconda, this lecture will use the following libraries:
!pip install --upgrade quantecon
Show code cell output
Requirement already satisfied: quantecon in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (0.7.2)
Requirement already satisfied: numba>=0.49.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (0.60.0)
Requirement already satisfied: numpy>=1.17.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (1.26.4)
Requirement already satisfied: requests in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (2.32.3)
Requirement already satisfied: scipy>=1.5.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (1.13.1)
Requirement already satisfied: sympy in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (1.13.2)
Requirement already satisfied: llvmlite<0.44,>=0.43.0dev0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from numba>=0.49.0->quantecon) (0.43.0)
Requirement already satisfied: charset-normalizer<4,>=2 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (3.3.2)
Requirement already satisfied: idna<4,>=2.5 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (3.7)
Requirement already satisfied: urllib3<3,>=1.21.1 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (2.2.3)
Requirement already satisfied: certifi>=2017.4.17 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (2024.8.30)
Requirement already satisfied: mpmath<1.4,>=1.1.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from sympy->quantecon) (1.3.0)
We’ll start with some imports:
import numpy as np
from quantecon import LQ
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
from matplotlib.ticker import FormatStrFormatter
import pandas as pd
from IPython.display import display, Math
42.2. Model Components#
There is no uncertainty.
Let:
\(p_t\) be the log of the price level
\(m_t\) be the log of nominal money balances
\(\theta_t = p_{t+1} - p_t\) be the net rate of inflation between \(t\) and \(t+1\)
\(\mu_t = m_{t+1} - m_t\) be the net rate of growth of nominal balances
The demand for real balances is governed by a discrete time version of Sargent and Wallace’s [Sargent and Wallace, 1973] perfect foresight version of a Cagan [Cagan, 1956] demand function for real balances:
for \(t \geq 0\).
Equation (42.1) asserts that the demand for real balances is inversely related to the public’s expected rate of inflation, which equals the actual rate of inflation because there is no uncertainty here.
(When there is no uncertainty, an assumption of rational expectations becomes equivalent to perfect foresight).
([Sargent, 1977] presents a rational expectations version of the model when there is uncertainty.)
Subtracting the demand function (42.1) at time \(t\) from the demand function at \(t+1\) gives:
or
Because \(\alpha > 0\), \(0 < \frac{\alpha}{1+\alpha} < 1\).
Definition: For scalar \(b_t\), let \(L^2\) be the space of sequences \(\{b_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) satisfying
We say that a sequence that belongs to \(L^2\) is square summable.
When we assume that the sequence \(\vec \mu = \{\mu_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) is square summable and we require that the sequence \(\vec \theta = \{\theta_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) is square summable, the linear difference equation (42.2) can be solved forward to get:
Insight: In the spirit of Chang [Chang, 1998], equations (42.1) and (42.3) show that \(\theta_t\) intermediates how choices of \(\mu_{t+j}, \ j=0, 1, \ldots\) impinge on time \(t\) real balances \(m_t - p_t = -\alpha \theta_t\).
An equivalence class of continuation money growth sequences \(\{\mu_{t+j}\}_{j=0}^\infty\) deliver the same \(\theta_t\).
We shall use this insight to help us simplify our analysis of alternative government policy problems.
That future rates of money creation influence earlier rates of inflation makes timing protocols matter for modeling optimal government policies.
When \(\vec \theta = \{\theta_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) is square summable, we can represent restriction (42.3) as
or
Even though \(\theta_0\) is to be determined by our model and so is not an initial condition, as it ordinarily would be in the state-space model described in our lecture on Linear Quadratic Control, we nevertheless write the model in the state-space form (42.5).
We use form (42.5) because we want to apply an approach described in our lecture on Stackelberg plans.
Notice that \(\frac{1+\alpha}{\alpha} > 1\) is an eigenvalue of transition matrix \(A\) that threatens to destabilize the state-space system.
The Ramsey planner will design a decision rule for \(\mu_t\) that stabilizes the system.
The government values a representative household’s utility of real balances at time \(t\) according to the utility function
The money demand function (42.1) and the utility function (42.6) imply that
42.3. Friedman’s Optimal Rate of Deflation#
According to (42.7), the bliss level
of real balances is \(\frac{u_1}{u_2}\) and the inflation rate that attains it is
Milton Friedman recommended that the government withdraw and destroy money at a rate that implies an inflation rate given by (42.8).
In our setting, that could be accomplished by setting
where \(\theta^*\) is given by equation (42.8).
To deduce this recommendation, Milton Friedman assumed that the taxes that government must impose in order to acquire money at rate \(\mu_t\) do not distort economic decisions.
for example, perhaps the government can impose lump sum taxes that distort no decisions by private agents
42.4. Calvo’s Distortion#
The starting point of Calvo [Calvo, 1978] and Chang [Chang, 1998] is that such lump sum taxes are not available.
Instead, the government acquires money by levying taxes that distort decisions and thereby impose costs on the representative consumer.
In the models of Calvo [Calvo, 1978] and Chang [Chang, 1998], the government takes those costs tax-distortion costs into account.
It balances the costs of imposing the distorting taxes needed to acquire the money that it destroys in order to generate deflation against the benefits that expected deflation generates by raising the representative households’ holdings of real balances.
Let’s see how the government does that in our version of the models of Calvo [Calvo, 1978] and Chang [Chang, 1998].
Via equation (42.3), a government plan \(\vec \mu = \{\mu_t \}_{t=0}^\infty\) leads to a sequence of inflation outcomes \(\vec \theta = \{ \theta_t \}_{t=0}^\infty\).
We assume that the government incurs social costs \(\frac{c}{2} \mu_t^2\) at \(t\) when it changes the stock of nominal money balances at rate \(\mu_t\).
Therefore, the one-period welfare function of a benevolent government is:
The government’s time \(0\) value is
where \(\beta \in (0,1)\) is a discount factor.
The government’s time \(t\) continuation value \(v_t\) is
We can represent dependence of \(v_0\) on \((\vec \theta, \vec \mu)\) recursively via the difference equation
It is useful to evaluate (42.12) under a time-invariant money growth rate \(\mu_t = \bar \mu\) that according to equation (42.3) would bring forth a constant inflation rate equal to \(\bar \mu\).
Under that policy,
for all \(t \geq 0\).
Values of \(V(\bar \mu)\) computed according to formula (42.13) for three different values of \(\bar \mu\) will play important roles below.
\(V(\mu^{MP})\) is the value of attained by the government in a Markov perfect equilibrium
\(V(\mu^R_\infty)\) is the value that a continuation Ramsey planner attains at \(t \rightarrow +\infty\)
We shall discover that \(V(\mu^R_\infty)\) is the worst continuation value attained along a Ramsey plan
\(V(\mu^{CR})\) is the value of attained by the government in a constrained to constant \(\mu\) equilibrium
42.5. Structure#
The following structure is induced by a representative agent’s behavior as summarized by the demand function for money (42.1) that leads to equation (42.3), which tells how future settings of \(\mu\) affect the current value of \(\theta\).
Equation (42.3) maps a policy sequence of money growth rates \(\vec \mu =\{\mu_t\}_{t=0}^\infty \in L^2\) into an inflation sequence \(\vec \theta = \{\theta_t\}_{t=0}^\infty \in L^2\).
These, in turn, induce a discounted value to a government sequence \(\vec v = \{v_t\}_{t=0}^\infty \in L^2\) that satisfies the recursion
where we have called \(s(\theta_t, \mu_t) = r(x_t, \mu_t)\), as in (42.11).
Thus, a triple of sequences \((\vec \mu, \vec \theta, \vec v)\) depends on a sequence \(\vec \mu \in L^2\).
At this point \(\vec \mu \in L^2\) is an arbitrary exogenous policy.
A theory of government decisions will make \(\vec \mu\) endogenous, i.e., a theoretical output instead of an input.
42.5.1. Intertemporal Aspects#
Criterion function (42.11) and the constraint system (42.5) exhibit the following structure:
Setting the money growth rate \(\mu_t \neq 0\) imposes costs \(\frac{c}{2} \mu_t^2\) at time \(t\) and at no other times; but
The money growth rate \(\mu_t\) affects the government’s one-period utilities at all dates \(s = 0, 1, \ldots, t\).
This structure sets the stage for the emergence of a time-inconsistent optimal government plan under a Ramsey timing protocol
it is also called a Stackelberg timing protocol.
We’ll study outcomes under a Ramsey timing protocol.
We’ll also study outcomes under other timing protocols.
42.6. Three Timing Protocols#
We consider three models of government policy making that differ in
what a policymaker chooses, either a sequence \(\vec \mu\) or just \(\mu_t\) in a single period \(t\).
when a policymaker chooses, either once and for all at time \(0\), or at some time or times \(t \geq 0\).
what a policymaker assumes about how its choice of \(\mu_t\) affects the representative agent’s expectations about earlier and later inflation rates.
In two of our models, a single policymaker chooses a sequence \(\{\mu_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) once and for all, knowing how \(\mu_t\) affects household one-period utilities at dates \(s = 0, 1, \ldots, t-1\)
these two models thus employ a Ramsey or Stackelberg timing protocol.
In a third model, there is a sequence of policymakers, each of whom sets \(\mu_t\) at one \(t\) only.
a time \(t\) policymaker cares only about \(v_t\) and ignores effects that its choice of \(\mu_t\) has on \(v_s\) at dates \(s = 0, 1, \ldots, t-1\).
The three models differ with respect to timing protocols, constraints on government choices, and government policymakers’ beliefs about how their decisions affect the representative agent’s beliefs about future government decisions.
The models are distinguished by their having either
A single Ramsey planner that chooses a sequence \(\{\mu_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) once and for all at time \(0\); or
A single Ramsey planner that chooses a sequence \(\{\mu_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) once and for all at time \(0\) subject to the constraint that \(\mu_t = \mu\) for all \(t \geq 0\); or
A sequence of distinct policymakers indexed by \(t =0, 1, 2, \ldots\)
a time \(t\) policymaker chooses \(\mu_t\) only and forecasts that future government decisions are unaffected by its choice.
The first model describes a Ramsey plan chosen by a Ramsey planner
The second model describes a Ramsey plan chosen by a Ramsey planner constrained to choose a time-invariant \(\mu_t\)
The third model describes a Markov perfect equilibrium
Note
In the quantecon lecture Sustainable Plans for a Calvo Model, we’ll study outcomes under another timing protocol in where there is a sequence of separate policymakers and a time \(t\) policymaker chooses only \(\mu_t\) but believes that its choice of \(\mu_t\) shapes the representative agent’s beliefs about future rates of money creation and inflation, and through them, future government actions. This is a model of a credible government policy also known as a sustainable plan. The relationship between outcomes in the first (Ramsey) timing protocol and the Sustainable Plans for a Calvo Model timing protocol and belief structure is the subject of a literature on sustainable or credible public policies (Chari and Kehoe [Chari and Kehoe, 1990] [Stokey, 1989], and Stokey [Stokey, 1991]).
42.7. Note on Dynamic Programming Squared#
We’ll begin with the timing protocol associated with a Ramsey plan and deploy an application of what we nickname dynamic programming squared.
The nickname refers to the feature that a value satisfying one Bellman equation appears as an argument in a value function associated with a second Bellman equation.
Thus, our models have involved two Bellman equations:
equation (42.1) expresses how \(\theta_t\) depends on \(\mu_t\) and \(\theta_{t+1}\)
equation (42.5) expresses how value \(v_t\) depends on \((\mu_t, \theta_t)\) and \(v_{t+1}\)
A value \(\theta\) from one Bellman equation appears as an argument of a second Bellman equation for another value \(v\).
42.8. A Ramsey Planner#
Here we consider a Ramsey planner that chooses \(\{\mu_t, \theta_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) to maximize (42.11) subject to the law of motion (42.5).
We can split this problem into two stages, as in the lecture Stackelberg plans and [Ljungqvist and Sargent, 2018] Chapter 19.
In the first stage, we take the initial inflation rate \(\theta_0\) as given and solve what looks like an ordinary LQ discounted dynamic programming problem.
In the second stage, we choose an optimal initial inflation rate \(\theta_0\).
Define a feasible set of \((\overrightarrow x_1, \overrightarrow \mu_0)\) sequences, both of which must belong to \(L^2\):
42.8.1. Subproblem 1#
The value function
satisfies the Bellman equation
subject to:
As in the lecture Stackelberg plans, we can map this problem into a linear-quadratic control problem and deduce an optimal value function \(J(x)\).
Guessing that \(J(x) = - x'Px\) and substituting into the Bellman equation gives rise to the algebraic matrix Riccati equation:
and an optimal decision rule
where
The QuantEcon LQ class solves for \(F\) and \(P\) given inputs \(Q, R, A, B\), and \(\beta\).
The value function for a (continuation) Ramsey planner is
or
or
where
The Ramsey plan for setting \(\mu_t\) is
or
where \(b_0 = -F_1, b_1 = - F_2\) and \(F\) satisfies equation (42.16),
The Ramsey planner’s decision rule for updating \(\theta_{t+1}\) is
where \(\begin{bmatrix} d_0 & d_1 \end{bmatrix}\) is the second row of the closed-loop matrix \(A - BF\) for computed in subproblem 1 above.
The linear quadratic control problem (42.15) satisfies regularity conditions that guarantee that \(A - BF \) is a stable matrix (i.e., its maximum eigenvalue is strictly less than \(1\) in absolute value).
Consequently, we are assured that
a stability condition that will play an important role.
It remains for us to describe how the Ramsey planner sets \(\theta_0\).
Subproblem 2 does that.
42.8.2. Subproblem 2#
The value of the Ramsey problem is
where \(V^R\) is the maximum value of \(v_0\) defined in equation (42.11).
We have taken the liberty of abusing notation slightly by writing \(J(x)\) as \(J(\theta)\)
notice that \(x = \begin{bmatrix} 1 \cr \theta \end{bmatrix}\), so \(\theta\) is the only component of \(x\) that can possibly vary
Value function \(J(\theta_0)\) satisfies
Maximizing \(J(\theta_0)\) with respect to \(\theta_0\) yields the FOC:
which implies
42.9. Representation of Ramsey Plan#
The preceding calculations indicate that we can represent a Ramsey plan \(\vec \mu\) recursively with the following system created in the spirit of Chang [Chang, 1998]:
where \(b_0, b_1, g_0, g_1, g_2\) are positive parameters that we shall compute with Python code below.
From condition (42.20), we know that \(|d_1| < 1\).
To interpret system (42.21), think of the sequence \(\{\theta_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) as a sequence of synthetic promised inflation rates.
For some purposes, we can think of these promised inflation rates just as computational devices for generating a sequence \(\vec\mu\) of money growth rates that when substituted into equation (42.3) generate actual rates of inflation.
It can be verified that if we substitute a plan \(\vec \mu = \{\mu_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) that satisfies these equations into equation (42.3), we obtain the same sequence \(\vec \theta\) generated by the system (42.21).
(Here an application of the Big \(K\), little \(k\) trick is again at work.)
Thus, within the Ramsey plan, promised inflation equals actual inflation.
System (42.21) implies that under the Ramsey plan
Because \(d_1 \in (0,1)\), it follows from (42.22) that as \(t \to \infty\) \(\theta_t^R \) converges to
Furthermore, we shall see that \(\theta_t^R\) converges to \(\theta_\infty^R\) from above.
Meanwhile, \(\mu_t\) varies over time according to
Variation of \( \vec \mu^R, \vec \theta^R, \vec v^R \) over time are symptoms of time inconsistency.
The Ramsey planner reaps immediate benefits from promising lower inflation later to be achieved by costly distorting taxes.
These benefits are intermediated by reductions in expected inflation that precede the reductions in money creation rates that rationalize them, as indicated by equation (42.3).
42.10. Multiple roles of \(\theta_t\)#
The inflation rate \(\theta_t\) plays three roles simultaneously:
In equation (42.3), \(\theta_t\) is the actual rate of inflation between \(t\) and \(t+1\).
In equation (42.2) and (42.3), \(\theta_t\) is also the public’s expected rate of inflation between \(t\) and \(t+1\).
In system (42.21), \(\theta_t\) is a promised rate of inflation chosen by the Ramsey planner at time \(0\).
That the same variable \(\theta_t\) takes on these multiple roles brings insights about commitment and forward guidance, about whether the government follows or leads the market, and about dynamic or time inconsistency.
42.11. Time inconsistency#
As discussed in Stackelberg plans and Optimal taxation with state-contingent debt, a continuation Ramsey plan is not a Ramsey plan.
This is a concise way of characterizing the time inconsistency of a Ramsey plan.
The time inconsistency of a Ramsey plan has motivated other models of government decision making that, relative to a Ramsey plan, alter either
the timing protocol and/or
assumptions about how government decision makers think their decisions affect the representative agent’s beliefs about future government decisions
42.12. Constrained-to-Constant-Growth-Rate Ramsey Plan#
We now describe a model in which we restrict the Ramsey planner’s choice set.
Instead of choosing a sequence of money growth rates \(\vec \mu \in {\bf L}^2\), we restrict the government to choose a time-invariant money growth rate \(\bar \mu\).
We created this version of the model to highlight an aspect of a Ramsey plan associated with its time inconsistency, namely, the feature that optimal settings of the policy instrument vary over time.
Thus, instead of allowing the government at time \(0\) to choose a different \(\mu_t\) for each \(t \geq 0\), we now assume that a government at time \(0\) once and for all chooses a constant sequence \(\mu_t = \bar \mu\) for all \(t \geq 0\).
We assume that the government knows the perfect foresight outcome implied by equation (42.2) that \(\theta_t = \bar \mu\) when \(\mu_t = \bar \mu\) for all \(t \geq 0\).
The government chooses \(\bar \mu\) to maximize
where \(V(\bar \mu)\) is defined in equation (42.13).
We can express \(V^{CR}(\bar \mu)\) as
With the quadratic form (42.6) for the utility function \(U\), the maximizing \(\bar \mu\) is
The optimal value attained by a constrained to constant \(\mu\) Ramsey planner is
Remark: We have introduced the constrained-to-constant \(\mu\) government in order eventually to highlight the time-variation of \(\mu_t\) that is a telltale sign of a Ramsey plan’s time inconsistency.
42.13. Markov Perfect Governments#
We now describe yet another timing protocol.
In this one, there is a sequence of government policymakers.
A time \(t\) government chooses \(\mu_t\) and expects all future governments to set \(\mu_{t+j} = \bar \mu\).
This assumption mirrors an assumption made in this QuantEcon lecture: Markov Perfect Equilibrium.
When it sets \(\mu_t\), the government at \(t\) believes that \(\bar \mu\) is unaffected by its choice of \(\mu_t\).
According to equation (42.3), the time \(t\) rate of inflation is then
which expresses inflation \(\theta_t\) as a geometric weighted average of the money growth today \(\mu_t\) and money growth from tomorrow onward \(\bar \mu\).
Given \(\bar \mu\), the time \(t\) government chooses \(\mu_t\) to maximize:
where \(V(\bar \mu)\) is given by formula (42.13) for the time \(0\) value \(v_0\) of recursion (42.12) under a money supply growth rate that is forever constant at \(\bar \mu\).
Substituting (42.28) into (42.29) and expanding gives:
The first-order necessary condition for maximing \(Q(\mu_t, \bar \mu)\) with respect to \(\mu_t\) is:
Rearranging we get the time \(t\) government’s best response map
where
A Markov Perfect Equilibrium (MPE) outcome \( \mu^{MPE}\) is a fixed point of the best response map:
Calculating \(\mu^{MPE}\), we find
This can be simplified to
The value of a Markov perfect equilibrium is
or
where \(V(\cdot)\) is given by formula (42.13).
Under the Markov perfect timing protocol
a government takes \(\bar \mu\) as given when it chooses \(\mu_t\)
we equate \(\mu_t = \mu\) only after we have computed a time \(t\) government’s first-order condition for \(\mu_t\).
42.14. Outcomes under Three Timing Protocols#
We want to compare outcome sequences \(\{ \theta_t,\mu_t \}\) under three timing protocols associated with
a standard Ramsey plan with its time varying \(\{ \theta_t,\mu_t \}\) sequences
a Markov perfect equilibrium
our nonstandard Ramsey plan in which the planner is restricted to choose a time-invariant \(\mu_t = \mu\) for all \(t \geq 0\).
We have computed closed form formulas for several of these outcomes, which we find it convenient to repeat here.
In particular, the constrained to constant inflation Ramsey inflation outcome is \(\mu^{CR}\), which according to equation (42.26) is
Equation (42.31) implies that the Markov perfect constant inflation rate is
According to equation (42.8), the bliss level of inflation that we associated with a Friedman rule is
Proposition 1: When \(c=0\), \(\theta^{MPE} = \theta^{CR} = \theta^*\) and \(\theta_0^R = \theta_\infty^R\).
The first two equalities follow from the preceding three equations.
We’ll illustrate the third equality that equates \(\theta_0^R\) to \( \theta_\infty^R\) with some quantitative examples below.
Proposition 1 draws attention to how a positive tax distortion parameter \(c\) alters the optimal rate of deflation that Milton Friedman financed by imposing a lump sum tax.
We’ll compute
\((\vec \theta^R, \vec \mu^R)\): ordinary time-varying Ramsey sequences
\((\theta^{MPE} = \mu^{MPE})\): Markov perfect equilibrium (MPE) fixed values
\((\theta^{CR} = \mu^{CR})\): fixed values associated with a constrained to time-invariant \(\mu\) Ramsey plan
\(\theta^*\): bliss level of inflation prescribed by a Friedman rule
We will create a class ChangLQ that solves the models and stores their values
class ChangLQ:
"""
Class to solve LQ Chang model
"""
def __init__(self, β, c, α=1, u0=1, u1=0.5, u2=3, T=1000, θ_n=200):
# Record parameters
self.α, self.u0, self.u1, self.u2 = α, u0, u1, u2
self.β, self.c, self.T, self.θ_n = β, c, T, θ_n
self.setup_LQ_matrices()
self.solve_LQ_problem()
self.compute_policy_functions()
self.simulate_ramsey_plan()
self.compute_θ_range()
self.compute_value_and_policy()
def setup_LQ_matrices(self):
# LQ Matrices
self.R = -np.array([[self.u0, -self.u1 * self.α / 2],
[-self.u1 * self.α / 2,
-self.u2 * self.α**2 / 2]])
self.Q = -np.array([[-self.c / 2]])
self.A = np.array([[1, 0], [0, (1 + self.α) / self.α]])
self.B = np.array([[0], [-1 / self.α]])
def solve_LQ_problem(self):
# Solve LQ Problem (Subproblem 1)
lq = LQ(self.Q, self.R, self.A, self.B, beta=self.β)
self.P, self.F, self.d = lq.stationary_values()
# Compute g0, g1, and g2 (41.16)
self.g0, self.g1, self.g2 = [-self.P[0, 0],
-2 * self.P[1, 0], -self.P[1, 1]]
# Compute b0 and b1 (41.17)
[[self.b0, self.b1]] = self.F
# Compute d0 and d1 (41.18)
self.cl_mat = (self.A - self.B @ self.F) # Closed loop matrix
[[self.d0, self.d1]] = self.cl_mat[1:]
# Solve Subproblem 2
self.θ_R = -self.P[0, 1] / self.P[1, 1]
# Find the bliss level of θ
self.θ_B = -self.u1 / (self.u2 * self.α)
def compute_policy_functions(self):
# Solve the Markov Perfect Equilibrium
self.μ_MPE = -self.u1 / ((1 + self.α) / self.α * self.c
+ self.α / (1 + self.α)
* self.u2 + self.α**2
/ (1 + self.α) * self.u2)
self.θ_MPE = self.μ_MPE
self.μ_CR = -self.α * self.u1 / (self.u2 * self.α**2 + self.c)
self.θ_CR = self.μ_CR
# Calculate value under MPE and CR economy
self.J_θ = lambda θ_array: - np.array([1, θ_array]) \
@ self.P @ np.array([1, θ_array]).T
self.V_θ = lambda θ: (self.u0 + self.u1 * (-self.α * θ)
- self.u2 / 2 * (-self.α * θ)**2
- self.c / 2 * θ**2) / (1 - self.β)
self.J_MPE = self.V_θ(self.μ_MPE)
self.J_CR = self.V_θ(self.μ_CR)
def simulate_ramsey_plan(self):
# Simulate Ramsey plan for large number of periods
θ_series = np.vstack((np.ones((1, self.T)), np.zeros((1, self.T))))
μ_series = np.zeros(self.T)
J_series = np.zeros(self.T)
θ_series[1, 0] = self.θ_R
[μ_series[0]] = -self.F.dot(θ_series[:, 0])
J_series[0] = self.J_θ(θ_series[1, 0])
for i in range(1, self.T):
θ_series[:, i] = self.cl_mat @ θ_series[:, i-1]
[μ_series[i]] = -self.F @ θ_series[:, i]
J_series[i] = self.J_θ(θ_series[1, i])
self.J_series = J_series
self.μ_series = μ_series
self.θ_series = θ_series
def compute_θ_range(self):
# Find the range of θ in Ramsey plan
θ_LB = min(min(self.θ_series[1, :]), self.θ_B)
θ_UB = max(max(self.θ_series[1, :]), self.θ_MPE)
θ_range = θ_UB - θ_LB
self.θ_LB = θ_LB - 0.05 * θ_range
self.θ_UB = θ_UB + 0.05 * θ_range
self.θ_range = θ_range
def compute_value_and_policy(self):
# Create the θ_space
self.θ_space = np.linspace(self.θ_LB, self.θ_UB, 200)
# Find value function and policy functions over range of θ
self.J_space = np.array([self.J_θ(θ) for θ in self.θ_space])
self.μ_space = -self.F @ np.vstack((np.ones(200), self.θ_space))
x_prime = self.cl_mat @ np.vstack((np.ones(200), self.θ_space))
self.θ_prime = x_prime[1, :]
self.CR_space = np.array([self.V_θ(θ) for θ in self.θ_space])
self.μ_space = self.μ_space[0, :]
# Calculate J_range, J_LB, and J_UB
self.J_range = np.ptp(self.J_space)
self.J_LB = np.min(self.J_space) - 0.05 * self.J_range
self.J_UB = np.max(self.J_space) + 0.05 * self.J_range
Let’s create an instance of ChangLQ with the following parameters:
clq = ChangLQ(β=0.85, c=2)
The following code plots value functions for a continuation Ramsey planner.
Show code cell source
def compute_θs(clq):
"""
Method to compute θ and assign corresponding labels and colors
Here clq is an instance of ChangLQ
"""
θ_points = [clq.θ_B, clq.θ_series[1, -1],
clq.θ_CR, clq.θ_space[np.argmax(clq.J_space)],
clq.θ_MPE]
labels = [r"$\theta^*$", r"$\theta_\infty^R$",
r"$\theta^{CR}$", r"$\theta_0^R$",
r"$\theta^{MPE}$"]
θ_colors = ['r', 'C5', 'g', 'C0', 'orange']
return θ_points, labels, θ_colors
def plot_policy_functions(clq):
"""
Method to plot the policy functions over the relevant range of θ
Here clq is an instance of ChangLQ
"""
fig, ax = plt.subplots(figsize=(8, 6))
θ_points, labels, θ_colors = compute_θs(clq)
# Plot θ' function
ax.plot(clq.θ_space, clq.θ_prime,
label=r"$\theta'(\theta)$",
lw=2, alpha=0.5, color='blue')
ax.plot(clq.θ_space, clq.θ_space, 'k--', lw=2, alpha=0.7) # Identity line
# Plot μ function
ax.plot(clq.θ_space, clq.μ_space, lw=2,
label=r"$\mu(\theta)$",
color='green', alpha=0.5)
# Plot labels and points for μ function
μ_min, μ_max = min(clq.μ_space), max(clq.μ_space)
μ_range = μ_max - μ_min
offset = 0.02 * μ_range
for θ, label in zip(θ_points, labels):
ax.scatter(θ, μ_min - offset, 60, color='black', marker='v')
ax.annotate(label, xy=(θ, μ_min - offset),
xytext=(θ - 0.012 * clq.θ_range, μ_min + 0.01 * μ_range),
fontsize=14)
# Set labels and limits
ax.set_xlabel(r"$\theta$", fontsize=18)
ax.set_xlim([clq.θ_LB, clq.θ_UB])
ax.set_ylim([min(clq.θ_LB, μ_min) - 0.05 * clq.θ_range,
max(clq.θ_UB, μ_max) + 0.05 * clq.θ_range])
# Add legend
ax.legend(fontsize=14)
plt.tight_layout()
plt.show()
plot_policy_functions(clq)
The dotted line in the above graph is the 45-degree line.
The blue line shows the choice of \(\theta_{t+1} = \theta'\) chosen by a continuation Ramsey planner who inherits \(\theta_t = \theta\).
The green line shows a continuation Ramsey planner’s choice of \(\mu_t = \mu\) as a function of an inherited \(\theta_t = \theta\).
Dynamics under the Ramsey plan are confined to \(\theta \in \left[ \theta_\infty^R, \theta_0^R \right]\).
The blue and green lines intersect each other and the 45-degree line at \(\theta =\theta_{\infty}^R\).
Notice that for \(\theta \in \left(\theta_\infty^R, \theta_0^R \right]\)
\(\theta' < \theta\) because the blue line is below the 45-degree line
\(\mu > \theta \) because the green line is above the 45-degree line
It follows that under the Ramsey plan \(\{\theta_t\}\) and \(\{\mu_t\}\) both converge monotonically from above to \(\theta_\infty^R\).
The next code plots the Ramsey planner’s value function \(J(\theta)\), which we know is maximized at \(\theta^R_0\), the promised inflation that the Ramsey planner sets at time \(t=0\).
The figure also plots the limiting value \(\theta_\infty^R\) to which the promised inflation rate \(\theta_t\) converges under the Ramsey plan.
In addition, the figure indicates an MPE inflation rate \(\theta^{MPE}\), \(\theta^{CR}\), and a bliss inflation \(\theta^*\).
Show code cell source
def plot_value_function(clq):
"""
Method to plot the value function over the relevant range of θ
Here clq is an instance of ChangLQ
"""
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
ax.set_xlim([clq.θ_LB, clq.θ_UB])
ax.set_ylim([clq.J_LB, clq.J_UB])
# Plot value function
ax.plot(clq.θ_space, clq.J_space, lw=2)
plt.xlabel(r"$\theta$", fontsize=18)
plt.ylabel(r"$J(\theta)$", fontsize=18)
θ_points, labels, _ = compute_θs(clq)
# Add points for θs
for θ, label in zip(θ_points, labels):
ax.scatter(θ, clq.J_LB + 0.02 * clq.J_range,
60, color='black', marker='v')
ax.annotate(label,
xy=(θ, clq.J_LB + 0.01 * clq.J_range),
xytext=(θ - 0.01 * clq.θ_range,
clq.J_LB + 0.08 * clq.J_range),
fontsize=14)
plt.tight_layout()
plt.show()
plot_value_function(clq)
In the above graph, notice that \(\theta^* < \theta_\infty^R < \theta^{CR} < \theta_0^R < \theta^{MPE} .\)
In some subsequent calculations, we’ll use our Python code to study how gaps between these outcome vary depending on parameters such as the cost parameter \(c\) and the discount factor \(\beta\).
42.15. Ramsey Planner’s Value Function#
The next code plots the Ramsey Planner’s value function \(J(\theta)\) as well as the value function of a constrained Ramsey planner who must choose a constant \(\mu\).
A time-invariant \(\mu\) implies a time-invariant \(\theta\), we take the liberty of labeling this value function \(V^{CR}(\theta)\).
We’ll use the code to plot \(J(\theta)\) and \(V^{CR}(\theta)\) for several values of the discount factor \(\beta\) and the cost of \(\mu_t^2\) parameter \(c\).
In all of the graphs below, we disarm the Proposition 1 equivalence results by setting \(c >0\).
The graphs reveal interesting relationships among \(\theta\)’s associated with various timing protocols:
\(\theta_0^R < \theta^{MPE} \): the initial Ramsey inflation rate exceeds the MPE inflation rate
\(\theta_\infty^R < \theta^{CR} <\theta_0^R\): the initial Ramsey deflation rate, and the associated tax distortion cost \(c \mu_0^2\) is less than the limiting Ramsey inflation rate \(\theta_\infty^R\) and the associated tax distortion cost \(\mu_\infty^2\)
\(\theta^* < \theta^R_\infty\): the limiting Ramsey inflation rate exceeds the bliss level of inflation
\(J(\theta) \geq V^{CR}(\theta)\)
\(J(\theta_\infty^R) = V^{CR}(\theta_\infty^R)\)
Before doing anything else, let’s write code to verify our claim that \(J(\theta_\infty^R) = V^{CR}(\theta_\infty^R)\).
Here is the code.
θ_inf = clq.θ_series[1, -1]
np.allclose(clq.J_θ(θ_inf),
clq.V_θ(θ_inf))
True
So our claim that \(J(\theta_\infty^R) = V^{CR}(\theta_\infty^R)\) is verified numerically.
Since \(J(\theta_\infty^R) = V^{CR}(\theta_\infty^R)\) occurs at a tangency point at which \(J(\theta)\) is increasing in \(\theta\), it follows that
with strict inequality when \(c > 0\).
Thus, the limiting continuation value of continuation Ramsey planners is worse that the constant value attained by a constrained-to-constant \(\mu_t\) Ramsey planner.
Now let’s write some code to plot outcomes under our three timing protocols.
Then we’ll use the code to explore how key parameters affect outcomes.
Show code cell source
def compare_ramsey_CR(clq, ax):
"""
Method to compare values of Ramsey and Constrained Ramsey (CR)
Here clq is an instance of ChangLQ
"""
# Calculate CR space range and bounds
min_CR, max_CR = min(clq.CR_space), max(clq.CR_space)
range_CR = max_CR - min_CR
l_CR, u_CR = min_CR - 0.05 * range_CR, max_CR + 0.05 * range_CR
# Set axis limits
ax.set_xlim([clq.θ_LB, clq.θ_UB])
ax.set_ylim([l_CR, u_CR])
# Plot J(θ) and v^CR(θ)
J_line, = ax.plot(clq.θ_space, clq.J_space, lw=2, label=r"$J(\theta)$")
CR_line, = ax.plot(clq.θ_space, clq.CR_space, lw=2, label=r"$V^{CR}(\theta)$")
# Mark key points
θ_points, labels, θ_colors = compute_θs(clq)
markers = [ax.scatter(θ, l_CR + 0.02 * range_CR, 60,
marker='v', label=label, color=color)
for θ, label, color in zip(θ_points, labels, θ_colors)]
# Plot lines at \theta_\infty^R, \theta^{CR}, and \theta^{MPE}
for i in [1, 2, -1]:
ax.axvline(θ_points[i], ymin=0.05, lw=2,
linestyle='--', color=θ_colors[i])
ax.axhline(y=clq.V_θ(θ_points[i]), linestyle='dotted',
lw=1.5, color=θ_colors[i], alpha=0.7)
v_CR = clq.V_θ(θ_points[2])
vcr_line = ax.axhline(y=v_CR, linestyle='--', lw=1.5,
color='black', alpha=0.7, label=r"$v^{CR}$")
return [J_line, CR_line, vcr_line], markers
def plt_clqs(clqs, axes):
"""
A helper function to plot two separate legends on top and bottom
Here clqs is a list of ChangLQ instances
axes is a list of Matplotlib axes
"""
line_handles, scatter_handles = {}, {}
for ax, clq in zip(axes, clqs):
lines, markers = compare_ramsey_CR(clq, ax)
ax.set_title(fr'$\beta$={clq.β}, $c$={clq.c}')
ax.tick_params(axis='x', rotation=45)
line_handles.update({line.get_label(): line for line in lines})
scatter_handles.update({marker.get_label(): marker for marker in markers})
# Collect handles and labels
line_handles = list(line_handles.values())
scatter_handles = list(scatter_handles.values())
# Create legends
fig = plt.gcf()
fig.legend(handles=line_handles,
labels=[line.get_label() for line in line_handles],
loc='upper center', ncol=4,
bbox_to_anchor=(0.5, 1.1), prop={'size': 12})
fig.legend(handles=scatter_handles,
labels=[marker.get_label() for marker in scatter_handles],
loc='lower center', ncol=5,
bbox_to_anchor=(0.5, -0.1), prop={'size': 12})
plt.tight_layout()
plt.show()
def generate_table(clqs, dig=3):
"""
A function to generate a table of θ values and display it using LaTeX
Here clqs is a list of ChangLQ instances and
dig is the number of digits to round to
"""
# Collect data
label_maps = {rf'$\beta={clq.β}, c={clq.c}$':
[f'{round(val, dig):.3f}' for val in compute_θs(clq)[0]] for clq in clqs}
labels = compute_θs(clqs[0])[1]
data_frame = pd.DataFrame(label_maps, index=labels)
# Generate table
columns = ' & '.join([f'\\text{{{col}}}' for col in data_frame.columns])
rows = ' \\\\\n'.join(
[' & '.join([f'\\text{{{label}}}'] + [f'{val}' for val in row])
for label, row in zip(data_frame.index, data_frame.values)])
latex_code = rf"""
\begin{{array}}{{{'c' * (len(data_frame.columns) + 1)}}}
& {columns} \\
\hline
{rows}
\end{{array}}
"""
display(Math(latex_code))
# Compare different β values
fig, axes = plt.subplots(1, 3, figsize=(12, 5))
β_values = [0.7, 0.8, 0.99]
clqs = [ChangLQ(β=β, c=2) for β in β_values]
plt_clqs(clqs, axes)
generate_table(clqs, dig=3)
The above graphs and table convey many useful things.
The horizontal dotted lines indicate values \(V(\mu_\infty^R), V(\mu^{CR}), V(\mu^{MPE}) \) of time-invariant money growth rates \(\mu_\infty^R, \mu^{CR}\) and \(\mu^{MPE}\), respectfully.
Notice how \(J(\theta)\) and \(V^{CR}(\theta)\) are tangent and increasing at \(\theta = \theta_\infty^R\), which implies that \(\theta^{CR} > \theta_\infty^R\) and \(J(\theta^{CR}) > J(\theta_\infty^R)\).
Notice how changes in \(\beta\) alter \(\theta_\infty^R\) and \(\theta_0^R\) but neither \(\theta^*, \theta^{CR}\), nor \(\theta^{MPE}\), in accord with formulas (42.8), (42.26), and (42.31), which imply that
But let’s see what happens when we change \(c\).
# Increase c to 100
fig, axes = plt.subplots(1, 3, figsize=(12, 5))
c_values = [1, 10, 100]
clqs = [ChangLQ(β=0.85, c=c) for c in c_values]
plt_clqs(clqs, axes)
generate_table(clqs, dig=4)
The above table and figures show how changes in \(c\) alter \(\theta_\infty^R\) and \(\theta_0^R\) as well as \(\theta^{CR}\) and \(\theta^{MPE}\), but not \(\theta^*,\) again in accord with formulas (42.8), (42.26), and (42.31).
Notice that as \(c \) gets larger and larger, \(\theta_\infty^R, \theta_0^R\) and \(\theta^{CR}\) all converge to \(\theta^{MPE}\).
Now let’s watch what happens when we drive \(c\) toward zero.
# Decrease c towards 0
fig, axes = plt.subplots(1, 3, figsize=(12, 5))
c_limits = [1, 0.1, 0.01]
clqs = [ChangLQ(β=0.85, c=c) for c in c_limits]
plt_clqs(clqs, axes)
The above graphs indicate that as \(c\) approaches zero, \(\theta_\infty^R, \theta_0^R, \theta^{CR}\), and \(\theta^{MPE}\) all approach \(\theta^*\).
This makes sense, because it was by adding costs of distorting taxes that Calvo [Calvo, 1978] drove a wedge between Friedman’s optimal deflation rate and the inflation rates chosen by a Ramsey planner.
The following code plots sequences \(\vec \mu\) and \(\vec \theta\) prescribed by a Ramsey plan as well as the constant levels \(\mu^{CR}\) and \(\mu^{MPE}\).
The following graphs report values for the value function parameters \(g_0, g_1, g_2\), and the Ramsey policy function parameters \(b_0, b_1, d_0, d_1\) associated with the indicated parameter pair \(\beta, c\).
We’ll vary \(\beta\) while keeping a small \(c\).
After that we’ll study consequences of raising \(c\).
We’ll watch how the decay rate \(d_1\) governing the dynamics of \(\theta_t^R\) is affected by alterations in the parameters \(\beta, c\).
Show code cell source
def plot_ramsey_MPE(clq, T=15):
"""
Method to plot Ramsey plan against Markov Perfect Equilibrium
Here clq is an instance of ChangLQ
"""
fig, axes = plt.subplots(1, 2, figsize=(12, 4))
plots = [clq.θ_series[1, 0:T], clq.μ_series[0:T]]
MPEs = [clq.θ_MPE, clq.μ_MPE]
labels = [r"\theta", r"\mu"]
for ax, plot, MPE, label in zip(axes, plots, MPEs, labels):
ax.plot(plot, label=fr"${label}^R$")
ax.hlines(MPE, 0, T-1, colors='orange', label=fr"${label}^{{MPE}}$")
if label == r"\theta":
ax.hlines(clq.θ_B, 0, T-1, colors='r', label=r"$\theta^*$")
ax.hlines(clq.μ_CR, 0, T-1, colors='g', label=fr"${label}^{{CR}}$")
ax.set_xlabel(r"$t$", fontsize=14)
ax.set_ylabel(fr"${label}_t$", fontsize=16)
ax.legend(loc='upper right')
fig.suptitle(fr'$\beta$={clq.β}, $c$={clq.c}', fontsize=16)
plt.tight_layout(rect=[0, 0.1, 1, 1])
plt.show()
def generate_param_table(clq):
"""
Method to generate a table of parameters
Here clq is an instance of ChangLQ
"""
# Collect data
param_names = [r'$g_0$', r'$g_1$', r'$g_2$',
r'$b_0$', r'$b_1$', r'$d_0$', r'$d_1$']
params = [clq.g0, clq.g1, clq.g2,
clq.b0, clq.b1, clq.d0, clq.d1]
# Generate table
label = rf'$\beta={clq.β}, c={clq.c}$'
data_frame = pd.DataFrame({label: params}, index=param_names).round(2).T
columns = ' & '.join([f'\\text{{{col}}}' for col in data_frame.columns])
rows = ' \\\\\n'.join([' & '.join([f'\\text{{{index}}}'] + [
f'{val}' for val in row]) for index, row in data_frame.iterrows()])
latex_code = rf"""
\begin{{array}}{{{'c' * (len(data_frame.columns) + 1)}}}
& {columns} \\
\hline
{rows}
\end{{array}}
"""
display(Math(latex_code))
for β in β_values:
clq = ChangLQ(β=β, c=2)
generate_param_table(clq)
plot_ramsey_MPE(clq)
Notice how \(d_1\) changes as we raise the discount factor parameter \(\beta\).
Now let’s study how increasing \(c\) affects \(\vec \theta, \vec \mu\) outcomes.
# Increase c to 100
for c in c_values:
clq = ChangLQ(β=0.85, c=c)
generate_param_table(clq)
plot_ramsey_MPE(clq)
Evidently, increasing \(c\) causes the decay factor \(d_1\) to increase.
Next, let’s look at consequences of increasing the demand for real balances parameter \(\alpha\) from its default value \(\alpha=1\) to \(\alpha=4\).
# Increase c to 100
for c in [10, 100]:
clq = ChangLQ(α=4, β=0.85, c=c)
generate_param_table(clq)
plot_ramsey_MPE(clq)
The above panels for an \(\alpha = 4\) setting indicate that \(\alpha\) and \(c\) affect outcomes in interesting ways.
We leave it to the reader to explore consequences of other constellations of parameter values.
42.15.1. Time Inconsistency of Ramsey Plan#
The variation over time in \(\vec \mu\) chosen by the Ramsey planner is a symptom of time inconsistency.
The Ramsey planner reaps immediate benefits from promising lower inflation later to be achieved by costly distorting taxes.
These benefits are intermediated by reductions in expected inflation that precede the reductions in money creation rates that rationalize them, as indicated by equation (42.3).
A government authority offered the opportunity to ignore effects on past utilities and to reoptimize at date \(t \geq 1\) would, if allowed, want to deviate from a Ramsey plan.
Note
A constrained-to-constant-\(\mu\) Ramsey plan is time consistent by construction. So is a Markov perfect plan.
42.15.2. Implausibility of Ramsey Plan#
Many economists regard a time inconsistent plan as implausible because they question the plausibility of timing protocol in which a plan for setting a sequence of policy variables is chosen once-and-for-all at time \(0\).
For that reason, the Markov perfect equilibrium concept attracts many economists.
A Markov perfect equilibrium plan is constructed to insure that a sequence of government policymakers who choose sequentially do not want to deviate from it.
The property of a Markov perfect equilibrium that there is no incentive to deviate from the plan makes it attractive.
42.16. Comparison of Equilibrium Values#
We have computed plans for
an ordinary (unrestricted) Ramsey planner who chooses a sequence \(\{\mu_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) at time \(0\)
a Ramsey planner restricted to choose a constant \(\mu\) for all \(t \geq 0\)
a Markov perfect sequence of governments
Below we compare equilibrium time zero values for these three.
We confirm that the value delivered by the unrestricted Ramsey planner exceeds the value delivered by the restricted Ramsey planner which in turn exceeds the value delivered by the Markov perfect sequence of governments.
clq.J_series[0]
6.776447396127581
clq.J_CR
6.756756756756755
clq.J_MPE
6.70875734810947
42.17. Digression on Timeless Perspective#
Our calculations have confirmed that \( \vec \mu^R, \vec \theta^R, \vec v^R \) are each monotone sequences that are bounded below and converge from above to limiting values.
Some authors are fond of focusing only on these limiting values.
They justify that by saying that they are taking a timeless perspective that ignores the transient movements in \( \vec \mu^R, \vec \theta^R, \vec v^R \) that are destined eventually to fade away as \(\theta_t\) described by Ramsey plan system (42.21) converges from above.
the timeless perspective pretends that Ramsey plan was actually solved long ago, and that we are stuck with it.
42.17.1. Ramsey Plan Strikes Back#
Research by Abreu [Abreu, 1988], Chari and Kehoe [Chari and Kehoe, 1990] [Stokey, 1989], and Stokey [Stokey, 1991] discovered conditions under which a Ramsey plan can be rescued from the complaint that it is not credible.
They accomplished this by expanding the description of a plan to include expectations about adverse consequences of deviating from it that can serve to deter deviations.
We turn to such theories in this quantecon lecture Sustainable Plans for a Calvo Model.