7. Tax Smoothing with Complete and Incomplete Markets#
In addition to what’s in Anaconda, this lecture uses the library:
!pip install --upgrade quantecon
Show code cell output
Requirement already satisfied: quantecon in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (0.7.2)
Requirement already satisfied: numba>=0.49.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (0.60.0)
Requirement already satisfied: numpy>=1.17.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (1.26.4)
Requirement already satisfied: requests in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (2.32.3)
Requirement already satisfied: scipy>=1.5.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (1.13.1)
Requirement already satisfied: sympy in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from quantecon) (1.13.2)
Requirement already satisfied: llvmlite<0.44,>=0.43.0dev0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from numba>=0.49.0->quantecon) (0.43.0)
Requirement already satisfied: charset-normalizer<4,>=2 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (3.3.2)
Requirement already satisfied: idna<4,>=2.5 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (3.7)
Requirement already satisfied: urllib3<3,>=1.21.1 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (2.2.3)
Requirement already satisfied: certifi>=2017.4.17 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from requests->quantecon) (2024.8.30)
Requirement already satisfied: mpmath<1.4,>=1.1.0 in /home/runner/miniconda3/envs/quantecon/lib/python3.12/site-packages (from sympy->quantecon) (1.3.0)
7.1. Overview#
This lecture describes tax-smoothing models that are counterparts to consumption-smoothing models in Consumption Smoothing with Complete and Incomplete Markets.
one is in the complete markets tradition of Lucas and Stokey [Lucas and Stokey, 1983].
the other is in the incomplete markets tradition of Barro [Barro, 1979].
Complete markets allow a government to buy or sell claims contingent on all possible Markov states.
Incomplete markets allow a government to buy or sell only a limited set of securities, often only a single risk-free security.
Barro [Barro, 1979] worked in an incomplete markets tradition by assuming that the only asset that can be traded is a risk-free one period bond.
In his consumption-smoothing model, Hall [Hall, 1978] had assumed an exogenous stochastic process of nonfinancial income and an exogenous gross interest rate on one period risk-free debt that equals \(\beta^{-1}\), where \(\beta \in (0,1)\) is also a consumer’s intertemporal discount factor.
Barro [Barro, 1979] made an analogous assumption about the risk-free interest rate in a tax-smoothing model that turns out to have the same mathematical structure as Hall’s consumption-smoothing model.
To get Barro’s model from Hall’s, all we have to do is to rename variables.
We maintain Hall’s and Barro’s assumption about the interest rate when we describe an incomplete markets version of our model.
In addition, we extend their assumption about the interest rate to an appropriate counterpart to create a “complete markets” model in the style of Lucas and Stokey [Lucas and Stokey, 1983].
7.1.1. Isomorphism between Consumption and Tax Smoothing#
For each version of a consumption-smoothing model, a tax-smoothing counterpart can be obtained simply by relabeling
consumption as tax collections
a consumer’s one-period utility function as a government’s one-period loss function from collecting taxes that impose deadweight welfare losses
a consumer’s nonfinancial income as a government’s purchases
a consumer’s debt as a government’s assets
Thus, we can convert the consumption-smoothing models in lecture Consumption Smoothing with Complete and Incomplete Markets into tax-smoothing models by setting \(c_t = T_t\), \(y_t = G_t\), and \(- b_t = a_t\), where \(T_t\) is total tax collections, \(\{G_t\}\) is an exogenous government expenditures process, and \(a_t\) is the government’s holdings of one-period risk-free bonds coming maturing at the due at the beginning of time \(t\).
For elaborations on this theme, please see Optimal Savings II: LQ Techniques and later parts of this lecture.
We’ll spend most of this lecture studying acquire finite-state Markov specification, but will also treat the linear state space specification.
7.1.1.1. Link to History#
For those who love history, President Thomas Jefferson’s Secretary of Treasury Albert Gallatin (1807) [Gallatin, 1837] seems to have prescribed policies that come from Barro’s model [Barro, 1979]
Let’s start with some standard imports:
import numpy as np
import quantecon as qe
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
To exploit the isomorphism between consumption-smoothing and tax-smoothing models, we simply use code from Consumption Smoothing with Complete and Incomplete Markets
7.1.2. Code#
Among other things, this code contains a function called consumption_complete()
.
This function computes \(\{ b(i) \}_{i=1}^{N}, \bar c\) as outcomes given a set of parameters for the general case with \(N\) Markov states under the assumption of complete markets
class ConsumptionProblem:
"""
The data for a consumption problem, including some default values.
"""
def __init__(self,
β=.96,
y=[2, 1.5],
b0=3,
P=[[.8, .2],
[.4, .6]],
init=0):
"""
Parameters
----------
β : discount factor
y : list containing the two income levels
b0 : debt in period 0 (= initial state debt level)
P : 2x2 transition matrix
init : index of initial state s0
"""
self.β = β
self.y = np.asarray(y)
self.b0 = b0
self.P = np.asarray(P)
self.init = init
def simulate(self, N_simul=80, random_state=1):
"""
Parameters
----------
N_simul : number of periods for simulation
random_state : random state for simulating Markov chain
"""
# For the simulation define a quantecon MC class
mc = qe.MarkovChain(self.P)
s_path = mc.simulate(N_simul, init=self.init, random_state=random_state)
return s_path
def consumption_complete(cp):
"""
Computes endogenous values for the complete market case.
Parameters
----------
cp : instance of ConsumptionProblem
Returns
-------
c_bar : constant consumption
b : optimal debt in each state
associated with the price system
Q = β * P
"""
β, P, y, b0, init = cp.β, cp.P, cp.y, cp.b0, cp.init # Unpack
Q = β * P # assumed price system
# construct matrices of augmented equation system
n = P.shape[0] + 1
y_aug = np.empty((n, 1))
y_aug[0, 0] = y[init] - b0
y_aug[1:, 0] = y
Q_aug = np.zeros((n, n))
Q_aug[0, 1:] = Q[init, :]
Q_aug[1:, 1:] = Q
A = np.zeros((n, n))
A[:, 0] = 1
A[1:, 1:] = np.eye(n-1)
x = np.linalg.inv(A - Q_aug) @ y_aug
c_bar = x[0, 0]
b = x[1:, 0]
return c_bar, b
def consumption_incomplete(cp, s_path):
"""
Computes endogenous values for the incomplete market case.
Parameters
----------
cp : instance of ConsumptionProblem
s_path : the path of states
"""
β, P, y, b0 = cp.β, cp.P, cp.y, cp.b0 # Unpack
N_simul = len(s_path)
# Useful variables
n = len(y)
y.shape = (n, 1)
v = np.linalg.inv(np.eye(n) - β * P) @ y
# Store consumption and debt path
b_path, c_path = np.ones(N_simul+1), np.ones(N_simul)
b_path[0] = b0
# Optimal decisions from (12) and (13)
db = ((1 - β) * v - y) / β
for i, s in enumerate(s_path):
c_path[i] = (1 - β) * (v - np.full((n, 1), b_path[i]))[s, 0]
b_path[i + 1] = b_path[i] + db[s, 0]
return c_path, b_path[:-1], y[s_path]
7.1.3. Revisiting the consumption-smoothing model#
The code above also contains a function called consumption_incomplete()
that uses (6.17) and (6.18) to
simulate paths of \(y_t, c_t, b_{t+1}\)
plot these against values of \(\bar c, b(s_1), b(s_2)\) found in a corresponding complete markets economy
Let’s try this, using the same parameters in both complete and incomplete markets economies
cp = ConsumptionProblem()
s_path = cp.simulate()
N_simul = len(s_path)
c_bar, debt_complete = consumption_complete(cp)
c_path, debt_path, y_path = consumption_incomplete(cp, s_path)
fig, ax = plt.subplots(1, 2, figsize=(14, 4))
ax[0].set_title('Consumption paths')
ax[0].plot(np.arange(N_simul), c_path, label='incomplete market')
ax[0].plot(np.arange(N_simul), np.full(N_simul, c_bar), label='complete market')
ax[0].plot(np.arange(N_simul), y_path, label='income', alpha=.6, ls='--')
ax[0].legend()
ax[0].set_xlabel('Periods')
ax[1].set_title('Debt paths')
ax[1].plot(np.arange(N_simul), debt_path, label='incomplete market')
ax[1].plot(np.arange(N_simul), debt_complete[s_path], label='complete market')
ax[1].plot(np.arange(N_simul), y_path, label='income', alpha=.6, ls='--')
ax[1].legend()
ax[1].axhline(0, color='k', ls='--')
ax[1].set_xlabel('Periods')
plt.show()
In the graph on the left, for the same sample path of nonfinancial income \(y_t\), notice that
consumption is constant when there are complete markets.
consumption takes a random walk in the incomplete markets version of the model.
the consumer’s debt oscillates between two values that are functions of the Markov state in the complete markets model.
the consumer’s debt drifts because it contains a unit root in the incomplete markets economy.
7.1.3.1. Relabeling variables to create tax-smoothing models#
As indicated above, we relabel variables to acquire tax-smoothing interpretations of the complete markets and incomplete markets consumption-smoothing models.
fig, ax = plt.subplots(1, 2, figsize=(14, 4))
ax[0].set_title('Tax collection paths')
ax[0].plot(np.arange(N_simul), c_path, label='incomplete market')
ax[0].plot(np.arange(N_simul), np.full(N_simul, c_bar), label='complete market')
ax[0].plot(np.arange(N_simul), y_path, label='govt expenditures', alpha=.6, ls='--')
ax[0].legend()
ax[0].set_xlabel('Periods')
ax[0].set_ylim([1.4, 2.1])
ax[1].set_title('Government assets paths')
ax[1].plot(np.arange(N_simul), debt_path, label='incomplete market')
ax[1].plot(np.arange(N_simul), debt_complete[s_path], label='complete market')
ax[1].plot(np.arange(N_simul), y_path, label='govt expenditures', ls='--')
ax[1].legend()
ax[1].axhline(0, color='k', ls='--')
ax[1].set_xlabel('Periods')
plt.show()
7.2. Tax Smoothing with Complete Markets#
It is instructive to focus on a simple tax-smoothing example with complete markets.
This example illustrates how, in a complete markets model like that of Lucas and Stokey [Lucas and Stokey, 1983], the government purchases insurance from the private sector.
Payouts from the insurance it had purchased allows the government to avoid raising taxes when emergencies make government expenditures surge.
We assume that government expenditures take one of two values \(G_1 < G_2\), where Markov state \(1\) means “peace” and Markov state \(2\) means “war”.
The government budget constraint in Markov state \(i\) is
where
is the price today of one unit of goods in Markov state \(j\) tomorrow when the Markov state is \(i\) today.
\(b_i\) is the government’s level of assets when it arrives in Markov state \(i\).
That is, \(b_i\) equals one-period state-contingent claims owed to the government that fall due at time \(t\) when the Markov state is \(i\).
Thus, if \(b_i < 0\), it means the government is owed \(b_i\) or owes \(-b_i\) when the economy arrives in Markov state \(i\) at time \(t\).
In our examples below, this happens when in a previous war-time period the government has sold an Arrow securities paying off \(- b_i\) in peacetime Markov state \(i\)
It can be enlightening to express the government’s budget constraint in Markov state \(i\) as
in which the term \((\sum_j Q_{ij} b_j - b_i)\) equals the net amount that the government spends to purchase one-period Arrow securities that will pay off next period in Markov states \(j = 1, \ldots, N\) after it has received payments \(b_i\) this period.
7.3. Returns on State-Contingent Debt#
Notice that \(\sum_{j'=1}^N Q_{ij'} b(j')\) is the amount that the government spends in Markov state \(i\) at time \(t\) to purchase one-period state-contingent claims that will pay off in Markov state \(j'\) at time \(t+1\).
Then the ex post one-period gross return on the portfolio of government assets held from state \(i\) at time \(t\) to state \(j\) at time \(t+1\) is
The cumulative return earned from putting \(1\) unit of time \(t\) goods into the government portfolio of state-contingent securities at time \(t\) and then rolling over the proceeds into the government portfolio each period thereafter is
Here is some code that computes one-period and cumulative returns on the government portfolio in the finite-state Markov version of our complete markets model.
Convention: In this code, when \(P_{ij}=0\), we arbitrarily set \(R(j | i)\) to be \(0\).
def ex_post_gross_return(b, cp):
"""
calculate the ex post one-period gross return on the portfolio
of government assets, given b and Q.
"""
Q = cp.β * cp.P
values = Q @ b
n = len(b)
R = np.zeros((n, n))
for i in range(n):
ind = cp.P[i, :] != 0
R[i, ind] = b[ind] / values[i]
return R
def cumulative_return(s_path, R):
"""
compute cumulative return from holding 1 unit market portfolio
of government bonds, given some simulated state path.
"""
T = len(s_path)
RT_path = np.empty(T)
RT_path[0] = 1
RT_path[1:] = np.cumprod([R[s_path[t], s_path[t+1]] for t in range(T-1)])
return RT_path
7.3.1. An Example of Tax Smoothing#
We’ll study a tax-smoothing model with two Markov states.
In Markov state \(1\), there is peace and government expenditures are low.
In Markov state \(2\), there is war and government expenditures are high.
We’ll compute optimal policies in both complete and incomplete markets settings.
Then we’ll feed in a particular assumed path of Markov states and study outcomes.
We’ll assume that the initial Markov state is state \(1\), which means we start from a state of peace.
The government then experiences 3 time periods of war and come back to peace again.
The history of Markov states is therefore \(\{ peace, war, war, war, peace \}\).
In addition, as indicated above, to simplify our example, we’ll set the government’s initial asset level to \(1\), so that \(b_1 = 1\).
Here’s code that itinitializes government assets to be unity in an initial peace time Markov state.
# Parameters
β = .96
# change notation y to g in the tax-smoothing example
g = [1, 2]
b0 = 1
P = np.array([[.8, .2],
[.4, .6]])
cp = ConsumptionProblem(β, g, b0, P)
Q = β * P
# change notation c_bar to T_bar in the tax-smoothing example
T_bar, b = consumption_complete(cp)
R = ex_post_gross_return(b, cp)
s_path = [0, 1, 1, 1, 0]
RT_path = cumulative_return(s_path, R)
print(f"P \n {P}")
print(f"Q \n {Q}")
print(f"Govt expenditures in peace and war = {g}")
print(f"Constant tax collections = {T_bar}")
print(f"Govt debts in two states = {-b}")
msg = """
Now let's check the government's budget constraint in peace and war.
Our assumptions imply that the government always purchases 0 units of the
Arrow peace security.
"""
print(msg)
AS1 = Q[0, :] @ b
# spending on Arrow security
# since the spending on Arrow peace security is not 0 anymore after we change b0 to 1
print(f"Spending on Arrow security in peace = {AS1}")
AS2 = Q[1, :] @ b
print(f"Spending on Arrow security in war = {AS2}")
print("")
# tax collections minus debt levels
print("Government tax collections minus debt levels in peace and war")
TB1 = T_bar + b[0]
print(f"T+b in peace = {TB1}")
TB2 = T_bar + b[1]
print(f"T+b in war = {TB2}")
print("")
print("Total government spending in peace and war")
G1 = g[0] + AS1
G2 = g[1] + AS2
print(f"Peace = {G1}")
print(f"War = {G2}")
print("")
print("Let's see ex-post and ex-ante returns on Arrow securities")
Π = np.reciprocal(Q)
exret = Π
print(f"Ex-post returns to purchase of Arrow securities = \n {exret}")
exant = Π * P
print(f"Ex-ante returns to purchase of Arrow securities \n {exant}")
print("")
print("The Ex-post one-period gross return on the portfolio of government assets")
print(R)
print("")
print("The cumulative return earned from holding 1 unit market portfolio of government bonds")
print(RT_path[-1])
P
[[0.8 0.2]
[0.4 0.6]]
Q
[[0.768 0.192]
[0.384 0.576]]
Govt expenditures in peace and war = [1, 2]
Constant tax collections = 1.2716883116883118
Govt debts in two states = [-1. -2.62337662]
Now let's check the government's budget constraint in peace and war.
Our assumptions imply that the government always purchases 0 units of the
Arrow peace security.
Spending on Arrow security in peace = 1.2716883116883118
Spending on Arrow security in war = 1.895064935064935
Government tax collections minus debt levels in peace and war
T+b in peace = 2.2716883116883118
T+b in war = 3.895064935064935
Total government spending in peace and war
Peace = 2.2716883116883118
War = 3.895064935064935
Let's see ex-post and ex-ante returns on Arrow securities
Ex-post returns to purchase of Arrow securities =
[[1.30208333 5.20833333]
[2.60416667 1.73611111]]
Ex-ante returns to purchase of Arrow securities
[[1.04166667 1.04166667]
[1.04166667 1.04166667]]
The Ex-post one-period gross return on the portfolio of government assets
[[0.78635621 2.0629085 ]
[0.5276864 1.38432018]]
The cumulative return earned from holding 1 unit market portfolio of government bonds
2.0860704239993675
7.3.2. Explanation#
In this example, the government always purchase \(1\) units of the Arrow security that pays off in peace time (Markov state \(1\)).
And it purchases a higher amount of the security that pays off in war time (Markov state \(2\)).
Thus, this is an example in which
during peacetime, the government purchases insurance against the possibility that war breaks out next period
during wartime, the government purchases insurance against the possibility that war continues another period
so long as peace continues, the ex post return on insurance against war is low
when war breaks out or continues, the ex post return on insurance against war is high
given the history of states that we assumed, the value of one unit of the portfolio of government assets eventually doubles in the end because of high returns during wartime.
We recommend plugging the quantities computed above into the government budget constraints in the two Markov states and staring.
Try changing the Markov transition matrix so that
Also, start the system in Markov state \(2\) (war) with initial government assets \(- 10\), so that the government starts the war in debt and \(b_2 = -10\).
7.4. More Finite Markov Chain Tax-Smoothing Examples#
To interpret some episodes in the fiscal history of the United States, we find it interesting to study a few more examples.
We compute examples in an \(N\) state Markov setting under both complete and incomplete markets.
These examples differ in how Markov states are jumping between peace and war.
To wrap procedures for solving models, relabeling graphs so that we record government debt rather than government assets, and displaying results, we construct a Python class.
class TaxSmoothingExample:
"""
construct a tax-smoothing example, by relabeling consumption problem class.
"""
def __init__(self, g, P, b0, states, β=.96,
init=0, s_path=None, N_simul=80, random_state=1):
self.states = states # state names
# if the path of states is not specified
if s_path is None:
self.cp = ConsumptionProblem(β, g, b0, P, init=init)
self.s_path = self.cp.simulate(N_simul=N_simul, random_state=random_state)
# if the path of states is specified
else:
self.cp = ConsumptionProblem(β, g, b0, P, init=s_path[0])
self.s_path = s_path
# solve for complete market case
self.T_bar, self.b = consumption_complete(self.cp)
self.debt_value = - (β * P @ self.b).T
# solve for incomplete market case
self.T_path, self.asset_path, self.g_path = \
consumption_incomplete(self.cp, self.s_path)
# calculate returns on state-contingent debt
self.R = ex_post_gross_return(self.b, self.cp)
self.RT_path = cumulative_return(self.s_path, self.R)
def display(self):
# plot graphs
N = len(self.T_path)
plt.figure()
plt.title('Tax collection paths')
plt.plot(np.arange(N), self.T_path, label='incomplete market')
plt.plot(np.arange(N), np.full(N, self.T_bar), label='complete market')
plt.plot(np.arange(N), self.g_path, label='govt expenditures', alpha=.6, ls='--')
plt.legend()
plt.xlabel('Periods')
plt.show()
plt.title('Government debt paths')
plt.plot(np.arange(N), -self.asset_path, label='incomplete market')
plt.plot(np.arange(N), -self.b[self.s_path], label='complete market')
plt.plot(np.arange(N), self.g_path, label='govt expenditures', ls='--')
plt.plot(np.arange(N), self.debt_value[self.s_path], label="value of debts today")
plt.legend()
plt.axhline(0, color='k', ls='--')
plt.xlabel('Periods')
plt.show()
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
ax.set_title('Cumulative return path (complete markets)')
line1 = ax.plot(np.arange(N), self.RT_path, color='blue')[0]
c1 = line1.get_color()
ax.set_xlabel('Periods')
ax.set_ylabel('Cumulative return', color=c1)
ax_ = ax.twinx()
line2 = ax_.plot(np.arange(N), self.g_path, ls='--', color='green')[0]
c2 = line2.get_color()
ax_.set_ylabel('Government expenditures', color=c2)
plt.show()
# plot detailed information
Q = self.cp.β * self.cp.P
print(f"P \n {self.cp.P}")
print(f"Q \n {Q}")
print(f"Govt expenditures in {', '.join(self.states)} = {self.cp.y.flatten()}")
print(f"Constant tax collections = {self.T_bar}")
print(f"Govt debt in {len(self.states)} states = {-self.b}")
print("")
print(f"Government tax collections minus debt levels in {', '.join(self.states)}")
for i in range(len(self.states)):
TB = self.T_bar + self.b[i]
print(f" T+b in {self.states[i]} = {TB}")
print("")
print(f"Total government spending in {', '.join(self.states)}")
for i in range(len(self.states)):
G = self.cp.y[i, 0] + Q[i, :] @ self.b
print(f" {self.states[i]} = {G}")
print("")
print("Let's see ex-post and ex-ante returns on Arrow securities \n")
print(f"Ex-post returns to purchase of Arrow securities:")
for i in range(len(self.states)):
for j in range(len(self.states)):
if Q[i, j] != 0.:
print(f" π({self.states[j]}|{self.states[i]}) = {1/Q[i, j]}")
print("")
exant = 1 / self.cp.β
print(f"Ex-ante returns to purchase of Arrow securities = {exant}")
print("")
print("The Ex-post one-period gross return on the portfolio of government assets")
print(self.R)
print("")
print("The cumulative return earned from holding 1 unit market portfolio of government bonds")
print(self.RT_path[-1])
7.4.1. Parameters#
γ = .1
λ = .1
ϕ = .1
θ = .1
ψ = .1
g_L = .5
g_M = .8
g_H = 1.2
β = .96
7.4.2. Example 1#
This example is designed to produce some stylized versions of tax, debt, and deficit paths followed by the United States during and after the Civil War and also during and after World War I.
We set the Markov chain to have three states
where the government expenditure vector \(g = \begin{bmatrix} g_L & g_H & g_M \end{bmatrix}\) where \(g_L < g_M < g_H\).
We set \(b_0 = 1\) and assume that the initial Markov state is state \(1\) so that the system starts off in peace.
These parameters have government expenditure beginning at a low level, surging during the war, then decreasing after the war to a level that exceeds its prewar level.
(This type of pattern occurred in the US Civil War and World War I experiences.)
g_ex1 = [g_L, g_H, g_M]
P_ex1 = np.array([[1-λ, λ, 0],
[0, 1-ϕ, ϕ],
[0, 0, 1]])
b0_ex1 = 1
states_ex1 = ['peace', 'war', 'postwar']
ts_ex1 = TaxSmoothingExample(g_ex1, P_ex1, b0_ex1, states_ex1, random_state=1)
ts_ex1.display()
P
[[0.9 0.1 0. ]
[0. 0.9 0.1]
[0. 0. 1. ]]
Q
[[0.864 0.096 0. ]
[0. 0.864 0.096]
[0. 0. 0.96 ]]
Govt expenditures in peace, war, postwar = [0.5 1.2 0.8]
Constant tax collections = 0.7548096885813149
Govt debt in 3 states = [-1. -4.07093426 -1.12975779]
Government tax collections minus debt levels in peace, war, postwar
T+b in peace = 1.754809688581315
T+b in war = 4.825743944636679
T+b in postwar = 1.8845674740484442
Total government spending in peace, war, postwar
peace = 1.754809688581315
war = 4.825743944636679
postwar = 1.8845674740484442
Let's see ex-post and ex-ante returns on Arrow securities
Ex-post returns to purchase of Arrow securities:
π(peace|peace) = 1.1574074074074074
π(war|peace) = 10.416666666666666
π(war|war) = 1.1574074074074074
π(postwar|war) = 10.416666666666666
π(postwar|postwar) = 1.0416666666666667
Ex-ante returns to purchase of Arrow securities = 1.0416666666666667
The Ex-post one-period gross return on the portfolio of government assets
[[0.7969336 3.24426428 0. ]
[0. 1.12278592 0.31159337]
[0. 0. 1.04166667]]
The cumulative return earned from holding 1 unit market portfolio of government bonds
0.17908622141460231
# The following shows the use of the wrapper class when a specific state path is given
s_path = [0, 0, 1, 1, 2]
ts_s_path = TaxSmoothingExample(g_ex1, P_ex1, b0_ex1, states_ex1, s_path=s_path)
ts_s_path.display()
P
[[0.9 0.1 0. ]
[0. 0.9 0.1]
[0. 0. 1. ]]
Q
[[0.864 0.096 0. ]
[0. 0.864 0.096]
[0. 0. 0.96 ]]
Govt expenditures in peace, war, postwar = [0.5 1.2 0.8]
Constant tax collections = 0.7548096885813149
Govt debt in 3 states = [-1. -4.07093426 -1.12975779]
Government tax collections minus debt levels in peace, war, postwar
T+b in peace = 1.754809688581315
T+b in war = 4.825743944636679
T+b in postwar = 1.8845674740484442
Total government spending in peace, war, postwar
peace = 1.754809688581315
war = 4.825743944636679
postwar = 1.8845674740484442
Let's see ex-post and ex-ante returns on Arrow securities
Ex-post returns to purchase of Arrow securities:
π(peace|peace) = 1.1574074074074074
π(war|peace) = 10.416666666666666
π(war|war) = 1.1574074074074074
π(postwar|war) = 10.416666666666666
π(postwar|postwar) = 1.0416666666666667
Ex-ante returns to purchase of Arrow securities = 1.0416666666666667
The Ex-post one-period gross return on the portfolio of government assets
[[0.7969336 3.24426428 0. ]
[0. 1.12278592 0.31159337]
[0. 0. 1.04166667]]
The cumulative return earned from holding 1 unit market portfolio of government bonds
0.9045311615620277
7.4.3. Example 2#
This example captures a peace followed by a war, eventually followed by a permanent peace .
Here we set
where the government expenditure vector \(g = \begin{bmatrix} g_L & g_L & g_H \end{bmatrix}\) and where \(g_L < g_H\).
We assume \(b_0 = 1\) and that the initial Markov state is state \(2\) so that the system starts off in a temporary peace.
g_ex2 = [g_L, g_L, g_H]
P_ex2 = np.array([[1, 0, 0],
[0, 1-γ, γ],
[ϕ, 0, 1-ϕ]])
b0_ex2 = 1
states_ex2 = ['peace', 'temporary peace', 'war']
ts_ex2 = TaxSmoothingExample(g_ex2, P_ex2, b0_ex2, states_ex2, init=1, random_state=1)
ts_ex2.display()
P
[[1. 0. 0. ]
[0. 0.9 0.1]
[0.1 0. 0.9]]
Q
[[0.96 0. 0. ]
[0. 0.864 0.096]
[0.096 0. 0.864]]
Govt expenditures in peace, temporary peace, war = [0.5 0.5 1.2]
Constant tax collections = 0.6053287197231834
Govt debt in 3 states = [ 2.63321799 -1. -2.51384083]
Government tax collections minus debt levels in peace, temporary peace, war
T+b in peace = -2.0278892733564
T+b in temporary peace = 1.6053287197231834
T+b in war = 3.1191695501730106
Total government spending in peace, temporary peace, war
peace = -2.0278892733564
temporary peace = 1.6053287197231834
war = 3.1191695501730106
Let's see ex-post and ex-ante returns on Arrow securities
Ex-post returns to purchase of Arrow securities:
π(peace|peace) = 1.0416666666666667
π(temporary peace|temporary peace) = 1.1574074074074074
π(war|temporary peace) = 10.416666666666666
π(peace|war) = 10.416666666666666
π(war|war) = 1.1574074074074074
Ex-ante returns to purchase of Arrow securities = 1.0416666666666667
The Ex-post one-period gross return on the portfolio of government assets
[[ 1.04166667 0. 0. ]
[ 0. 0.90470824 2.27429251]
[-1.37206116 0. 1.30985865]]
The cumulative return earned from holding 1 unit market portfolio of government bonds
-9.368991732594216
7.4.4. Example 3#
This example features a situation in which one of the states is a war state with no hope of peace next period, while another state is a war state with a positive probability of peace next period.
The Markov chain is:
with government expenditure levels for the four states being \(\begin{bmatrix} g_L & g_L & g_H & g_H \end{bmatrix}\) where \(g_L < g_H\).
We start with \(b_0 = 1\) and \(s_0 = 1\).
g_ex3 = [g_L, g_L, g_H, g_H]
P_ex3 = np.array([[1-λ, λ, 0, 0],
[0, 1-ϕ, ϕ, 0],
[0, 0, 1-ψ, ψ],
[θ, 0, 0, 1-θ ]])
b0_ex3 = 1
states_ex3 = ['peace1', 'peace2', 'war1', 'war2']
ts_ex3 = TaxSmoothingExample(g_ex3, P_ex3, b0_ex3, states_ex3, random_state=1)
ts_ex3.display()
P
[[0.9 0.1 0. 0. ]
[0. 0.9 0.1 0. ]
[0. 0. 0.9 0.1]
[0.1 0. 0. 0.9]]
Q
[[0.864 0.096 0. 0. ]
[0. 0.864 0.096 0. ]
[0. 0. 0.864 0.096]
[0.096 0. 0. 0.864]]
Govt expenditures in peace1, peace2, war1, war2 = [0.5 0.5 1.2 1.2]
Constant tax collections = 0.6927944572748268
Govt debt in 4 states = [-1. -3.42494226 -6.86027714 -4.43533487]
Government tax collections minus debt levels in peace1, peace2, war1, war2
T+b in peace1 = 1.6927944572748268
T+b in peace2 = 4.117736720554273
T+b in war1 = 7.553071593533488
T+b in war2 = 5.128129330254041
Total government spending in peace1, peace2, war1, war2
peace1 = 1.6927944572748268
peace2 = 4.117736720554273
war1 = 7.553071593533487
war2 = 5.128129330254041
Let's see ex-post and ex-ante returns on Arrow securities
Ex-post returns to purchase of Arrow securities:
π(peace1|peace1) = 1.1574074074074074
π(peace2|peace1) = 10.416666666666666
π(peace2|peace2) = 1.1574074074074074
π(war1|peace2) = 10.416666666666666
π(war1|war1) = 1.1574074074074074
π(war2|war1) = 10.416666666666666
π(peace1|war2) = 10.416666666666666
π(war2|war2) = 1.1574074074074074
Ex-ante returns to purchase of Arrow securities = 1.0416666666666667
The Ex-post one-period gross return on the portfolio of government assets
[[0.83836741 2.87135998 0. 0. ]
[0. 0.94670854 1.89628977 0. ]
[0. 0. 1.07983627 0.69814023]
[0.2545741 0. 0. 1.1291214 ]]
The cumulative return earned from holding 1 unit market portfolio of government bonds
0.02371440178864222
7.4.5. Example 4#
Here the Markov chain is:
with government expenditure levels for the five states being \(\begin{bmatrix} g_L & g_L & g_H & g_H & g_L \end{bmatrix}\) where \(g_L < g_H\).
We ssume that \(b_0 = 1\) and \(s_0 = 1\).
g_ex4 = [g_L, g_L, g_H, g_H, g_L]
P_ex4 = np.array([[1-λ, λ, 0, 0, 0],
[0, 1-ϕ, ϕ, 0, 0],
[0, 0, 1-ψ, ψ, 0],
[0, 0, 0, 1-θ, θ],
[0, 0, 0, 0, 1]])
b0_ex4 = 1
states_ex4 = ['peace1', 'peace2', 'war1', 'war2', 'permanent peace']
ts_ex4 = TaxSmoothingExample(g_ex4, P_ex4, b0_ex4, states_ex4, random_state=1)
ts_ex4.display()
P
[[0.9 0.1 0. 0. 0. ]
[0. 0.9 0.1 0. 0. ]
[0. 0. 0.9 0.1 0. ]
[0. 0. 0. 0.9 0.1]
[0. 0. 0. 0. 1. ]]
Q
[[0.864 0.096 0. 0. 0. ]
[0. 0.864 0.096 0. 0. ]
[0. 0. 0.864 0.096 0. ]
[0. 0. 0. 0.864 0.096]
[0. 0. 0. 0. 0.96 ]]
Govt expenditures in peace1, peace2, war1, war2, permanent peace = [0.5 0.5 1.2 1.2 0.5]
Constant tax collections = 0.6349979047185738
Govt debt in 5 states = [-1. -2.82289484 -5.4053292 -1.77211121 3.37494762]
Government tax collections minus debt levels in peace1, peace2, war1, war2, permanent peace
T+b in peace1 = 1.6349979047185736
T+b in peace2 = 3.4578927455370505
T+b in war1 = 6.040327103363229
T+b in war2 = 2.4071091102836433
T+b in permanent peace = -2.7399497132457697
Total government spending in peace1, peace2, war1, war2, permanent peace
peace1 = 1.6349979047185736
peace2 = 3.457892745537051
war1 = 6.040327103363228
war2 = 2.407109110283643
permanent peace = -2.7399497132457697
Let's see ex-post and ex-ante returns on Arrow securities
Ex-post returns to purchase of Arrow securities:
π(peace1|peace1) = 1.1574074074074074
π(peace2|peace1) = 10.416666666666666
π(peace2|peace2) = 1.1574074074074074
π(war1|peace2) = 10.416666666666666
π(war1|war1) = 1.1574074074074074
π(war2|war1) = 10.416666666666666
π(war2|war2) = 1.1574074074074074
π(permanent peace|war2) = 10.416666666666666
π(permanent peace|permanent peace) = 1.0416666666666667
Ex-ante returns to purchase of Arrow securities = 1.0416666666666667
The Ex-post one-period gross return on the portfolio of government assets
[[ 0.8810589 2.48713661 0. 0. 0. ]
[ 0. 0.95436011 1.82742569 0. 0. ]
[ 0. 0. 1.11672808 0.36611394 0. ]
[ 0. 0. 0. 1.46806216 -2.79589276]
[ 0. 0. 0. 0. 1.04166667]]
The cumulative return earned from holding 1 unit market portfolio of government bonds
-11.132109773063616
7.4.6. Example 5#
The example captures a case when the system follows a deterministic path from peace to war, and back to peace again.
Since there is no randomness, the outcomes in complete markets setting should be the same as in incomplete markets setting.
The Markov chain is:
with government expenditure levels for the seven states being \(\begin{bmatrix} g_L & g_L & g_H & g_H & g_H & g_H & g_L \end{bmatrix}\) where \(g_L < g_H\). Assume \(b_0 = 1\) and \(s_0 = 1\).
g_ex5 = [g_L, g_L, g_H, g_H, g_H, g_H, g_L]
P_ex5 = np.array([[0, 1, 0, 0, 0, 0, 0],
[0, 0, 1, 0, 0, 0, 0],
[0, 0, 0, 1, 0, 0, 0],
[0, 0, 0, 0, 1, 0, 0],
[0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 1, 0],
[0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 1],
[0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 0, 1]])
b0_ex5 = 1
states_ex5 = ['peace1', 'peace2', 'war1', 'war2', 'war3', 'permanent peace']
ts_ex5 = TaxSmoothingExample(g_ex5, P_ex5, b0_ex5, states_ex5, N_simul=7, random_state=1)
ts_ex5.display()
P
[[0 1 0 0 0 0 0]
[0 0 1 0 0 0 0]
[0 0 0 1 0 0 0]
[0 0 0 0 1 0 0]
[0 0 0 0 0 1 0]
[0 0 0 0 0 0 1]
[0 0 0 0 0 0 1]]
Q
[[0. 0.96 0. 0. 0. 0. 0. ]
[0. 0. 0.96 0. 0. 0. 0. ]
[0. 0. 0. 0.96 0. 0. 0. ]
[0. 0. 0. 0. 0.96 0. 0. ]
[0. 0. 0. 0. 0. 0.96 0. ]
[0. 0. 0. 0. 0. 0. 0.96]
[0. 0. 0. 0. 0. 0. 0.96]]
Govt expenditures in peace1, peace2, war1, war2, war3, permanent peace = [0.5 0.5 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.2 0.5]
Constant tax collections = 0.5571895472128001
Govt debt in 6 states = [-1. -1.10123911 -1.20669652 -0.58738132 0.05773868 0.72973868
1.42973868]
Government tax collections minus debt levels in peace1, peace2, war1, war2, war3, permanent peace
T+b in peace1 = 1.5571895472128001
T+b in peace2 = 1.6584286588928001
T+b in war1 = 1.7638860668928005
T+b in war2 = 1.1445708668928003
T+b in war3 = 0.4994508668928004
T+b in permanent peace = -0.17254913310719955
Total government spending in peace1, peace2, war1, war2, war3, permanent peace
peace1 = 1.5571895472128
peace2 = 1.6584286588928003
war1 = 1.7638860668928
war2 = 1.1445708668928003
war3 = 0.49945086689280027
permanent peace = -0.17254913310719933
Let's see ex-post and ex-ante returns on Arrow securities
Ex-post returns to purchase of Arrow securities:
π(peace2|peace1) = 1.0416666666666667
π(war1|peace2) = 1.0416666666666667
π(war2|war1) = 1.0416666666666667
π(war3|war2) = 1.0416666666666667
π(permanent peace|war3) = 1.0416666666666667
Ex-ante returns to purchase of Arrow securities = 1.0416666666666667
The Ex-post one-period gross return on the portfolio of government assets
[[0. 1.04166667 0. 0. 0. 0.
0. ]
[0. 0. 1.04166667 0. 0. 0.
0. ]
[0. 0. 0. 1.04166667 0. 0.
0. ]
[0. 0. 0. 0. 1.04166667 0.
0. ]
[0. 0. 0. 0. 0. 1.04166667
0. ]
[0. 0. 0. 0. 0. 0.
1.04166667]
[0. 0. 0. 0. 0. 0.
1.04166667]]
The cumulative return earned from holding 1 unit market portfolio of government bonds
1.2775343959060068
7.4.7. Continuous-State Gaussian Model#
To construct a tax-smoothing version of the complete markets consumption-smoothing model with a continuous state space that we presented in the lecture consumption smoothing with complete and incomplete markets, we simply relabel variables.
Thus, a government faces a sequence of budget constraints
where \(T_t\) is tax revenues, \(b_t\) are receipts at \(t\) from contingent claims that the government had purchased at time \(t-1\), and
is the value of time \(t+1\) state-contingent claims purchased by the government at time \(t\).
As above with the consumption-smoothing model, we can solve the time \(t\) budget constraint forward to obtain
which can be rearranged to become
which states that the present value of government purchases equals the value of government assets at \(t\) plus the present value of tax receipts.
With these relabelings, examples presented in consumption smoothing with complete and incomplete markets can be interpreted as tax-smoothing models.
Returns: In the continuous state version of our incomplete markets model, the ex post one-period gross rate of return on the government portfolio equals